marni是什么牌子| 溜肩是什么意思| 欣赏什么| 一什么杨桃| 什么东西补气血效果最好| 心绞痛用什么药最好| 吃花生米是什么意思| 门前的小树已成年是什么歌| 脂肪酸是什么| 文竹的寓意是什么| 绾色是什么颜色| 什么叫相向而行| 秋天的落叶像什么| 蟹黄是螃蟹的什么东西| 腋下出汗有异味是什么原因| 焦虑症是什么意思| 12月2日是什么星座| 秋葵什么时候种植最好| 飞机杯是什么东西| 俄罗斯人是什么人种| 女人小腹坠痛是什么原因| 梦见挖坟墓预示什么| 10月19号什么星座| gi食物是什么意思| 高血压可以吃什么肉| 什么是三公经费| 检查肝肾功能挂什么科| 听诊器能听出什么| 胃不好的人适合吃什么水果| 房子什么朝向好| 6月28什么星座| 乌龟肺炎用什么药| 什么手组词| 软坚散结是什么意思| 辰砂和朱砂有什么区别| 怀孕前一周有什么症状| 化疗期间吃什么水果好| 跖疣用什么药| 什么猫掉毛少| 妇科彩超主要检查什么| 什么的梦境| 嘴巴苦是什么原因引起的| 17数字代表什么意思| 肾积水有什么症状表现| 孩子拉肚子吃什么食物好| 癫疯病发作前兆有什么症状| 白萝卜什么时候种| 癫痫病是什么原因引起的| 做俯卧撑有什么好处| 臭屁是什么意思| 鲤鱼喜欢吃什么食物| 喉咙长期有痰是什么原因| pku是什么意思| 芒果和什么榨汁好喝| dvf是什么品牌| 绽开什么| 什么叫元素| 血铅是什么| 牛大力是什么| 鼻尖出汗是什么原因| 月经下不来吃什么药| 梦遗是什么| 竖心旁的字与什么有关| 羲字五行属什么| 七月初八是什么星座| 脑血栓不能吃什么水果| 小脑萎缩吃什么药效果最好| 国药准字号是什么意思| 蒲公英可以和什么一起泡水喝| 性向是什么意思| 眼皮浮肿是什么原因引起的| 白细胞高是什么意思| 抽电子烟有什么危害| 脚底板痛挂什么科| 湖北人喜欢吃什么菜| 什么是内卷| 北京有什么特产好吃| 一拃是什么意思| 十月一日什么星座| 梦见穿山甲预示着什么| 疣是什么病毒| 身怀六甲什么意思| 姨妈有血块是什么原因| 脚突然抽筋是什么原因| 大姨妈期间不能吃什么东西| 挂妇科门诊都检查什么| 梦到乌龟是什么意思| zing是什么意思| 6月17什么星座| 8月23日是什么星座| 梅花三弄的三弄指什么| 什么水果对肝脏好| 做生意的人最忌讳什么| oct试验是什么| 双性人是什么意思| 加应子是什么水果| 玫瑰什么时候开花| 副检察长什么级别| 体外射精什么意思| 流产后吃什么水果好| 大仙为什么知道你的事| 古井贡酒属于什么档次| 一月底是什么星座| 齐博林手表是什么档次| 梦见生孩子是什么意思| 真情流露是什么意思| 漂洗和洗涤有什么区别| hb什么意思| 子宫内膜回声欠均匀什么意思| 宰相肚里能撑船是什么意思| 狗鼻子为什么是湿的| 什么食物不能一起吃| 国企是什么编制| 2001年什么年| 亨廷顿舞蹈症是什么病| 外阴白斑是什么病| 藤椒是什么| 猪肉炖什么好吃| 单位是什么| 有什么症状是肯定没怀孕| 玫瑰花泡水喝有什么功效| 大人有大量是什么意思| k代表什么| 梦见借给别人钱是什么意思| 急性肠胃炎是什么原因引起的| 死党什么意思| 贤良淑德后半句是什么| 电势是什么| 什么是终端| 黄瓜不能和什么食物一起吃| 什么不迫| 什么睡姿对髋关节好| 申是什么意思| 五月10号是什么星座| 美业是什么| 排卵日和排卵期有什么区别| 二十七岁属什么生肖| 怀孕之后身体有什么变化| 宝宝病毒性感冒吃什么药效果好| 打胎后要注意什么| 石花菜是什么植物| 属兔本命佛是什么佛| 为什么清真不吃猪肉| 混社会的人一般干什么| 惨不忍睹是什么意思| 血脂高是什么原因引起的| 老鼠和什么属相最配对| 汪字五行属什么| 嘛哩嘛哩哄是什么意思| 同型半胱氨酸高吃什么药| 188是什么意思| 什么的小莲蓬| 切除痣挂什么科| 灵芝泡水喝有什么好处| 知了吃什么食物| 3.14什么星座| 滑精是什么原因| 腰疼肚子疼是什么原因引起的| 蛇蛋是什么样子的| lp是什么意思| 卵巢多囊是什么意思| 右手大拇指抖动是什么原因| 缺镁吃什么药| 玉米什么的什么的| 2e是什么意思| 1973年属牛的是什么命| 谷丙转氨酶偏高吃什么好| 东莞有什么好玩的| 吃什么水果能降血压| 撮鸟是什么意思| 星星为什么会眨眼睛| 丙型肝炎吃什么药最好| 腿麻是什么原因引起的| 痔疮肛瘘是什么症状| 1月10日什么星座| 02年属什么| 无奇不有是什么意思| 西辽国在现今什么地方| 鲁是什么意思| 皮上长小肉疙瘩是什么| 尿酸高吃什么中药能降下来| 耳浴10分钟什么意思| 四级士官是什么级别| 夏天感冒咳嗽吃什么药| 肚子拉稀是什么原因| 什么是接触性出血| 今天吃什么| 夜间睡觉流口水是什么原因| 上呼吸道感染吃什么| lot是什么| 老觉得饿是什么原因| 蛇酒不是三十九开什么| 什么是笑气| 肺纹理增多什么意思| 弥留之际什么意思| NG是什么| 台风什么时候到福建| 被口什么感觉| 灰指甲用什么药效果好| 什么叫间质瘤| 什么原因导致阴虚| 么么叽是什么意思| 长残了是什么意思| 自然人是什么意思| 幽门螺杆菌是什么意思| 落拓是什么意思| 神经性头疼吃什么药效果好| 三七粉什么人不适合吃| 做流产手术需要准备什么东西| 失眠什么原因| 气血不足挂什么科| 女字旁一个朱念什么| 胰腺不好吃什么食物好| 喉咙痛感冒吃什么药| 孕期吃什么补铁| 晚上睡不着白天睡不醒是什么原因| 梦到自己被蛇咬是什么意思| 结婚前要准备什么| 记性不好吃什么药| 女性尿出血是什么原因| 意淫是什么意思| 脑瘫是什么原因引起的| 外阴白斑是什么病| 八一是什么节| 脂溢性皮炎是什么症状| 前列腺b超能检查出什么| 痛经吃什么| mh是什么意思| 感冒发烧可以吃什么水果| 男人不长胡子是什么原因| 指甲盖有竖纹是什么原因| 用维生素e擦脸有什么好处和坏处| 卧蚕是什么| 9月1号什么星座| 闺蜜过生日送什么礼物好| 词牌名什么意思| 手指关节疼痛用什么药| 下肢血液循环不好吃什么药| 六六大顺是什么生肖| 女人的排卵期一般是什么时候| 什么植物驱蚊效果最好| 油皮适合用什么护肤品| 娇喘是什么| 狗狗睡姿代表什么图解| 郁郁寡欢的意思是什么| 男性b超检查什么项目| 樟脑是什么东西| 七月份适合种什么菜| 民族是什么意思| 例假期间适合吃什么水果| 脂肪瘤是什么原因引起的| 吐鲁番为什么那么热| 食管鳞状上皮增生是什么意思| 九月份有什么节日| 医院康复科是干什么的| 卵巢增大是什么原因引起的| 傻白甜是什么意思| 负心汉是什么意思| 梦见被狼追是什么意思| 冒汗是什么原因| 水瓶座前面是什么星座| 路由器坏了有什么症状| 啪啪啪是什么意思| 搬家 送什么| 百度Jump to content

CBA集锦-易建联砍大两双伤退 吉林113-119广东;

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
An estimation of the CAPM and the security market line (purple) for the Dow Jones Industrial Average over 3 years for monthly data.
百度 动力方面,美版车型采用全新的升排量直喷汽油发动机,匹配6速手动或CVT无级变速器。

In finance, the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) is a model used to determine a theoretically appropriate required rate of return of an asset, to make decisions about adding assets to a well-diversified portfolio.

The model takes into account the asset's sensitivity to non-diversifiable risk (also known as systematic risk or market risk), often represented by the quantity beta (β) in the financial industry, as well as the expected return of the market and the expected return of a theoretical risk-free asset. CAPM assumes a particular form of utility functions (in which only first and second moments matter, that is risk is measured by variance, for example a quadratic utility) or alternatively asset returns whose probability distributions are completely described by the first two moments (for example, the normal distribution) and zero transaction costs (necessary for diversification to get rid of all idiosyncratic risk). Under these conditions, CAPM shows that the cost of equity capital is determined only by beta.[1][2] Despite its failing numerous empirical tests,[3] and the existence of more modern approaches to asset pricing and portfolio selection (such as arbitrage pricing theory and Merton's portfolio problem), the CAPM still remains popular due to its simplicity and utility in a variety of situations.

Inventors

[edit]

The CAPM was introduced by Jack Treynor (1961, 1962),[4] William F. Sharpe (1964), John Lintner (1965a,b) and Jan Mossin (1966) independently, building on the earlier work of Harry Markowitz on diversification and modern portfolio theory. Sharpe, Markowitz and Merton Miller jointly received the 1990 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics for this contribution to the field of financial economics. Fischer Black (1972) developed another version of CAPM, called Black CAPM or zero-beta CAPM, that does not assume the existence of a riskless asset. This version was more robust against empirical testing and was influential in the widespread adoption of the CAPM.

Formula

[edit]

The CAPM is a model for pricing an individual security or portfolio. For individual securities, we make use of the security market line (SML) and its relation to expected return and systematic risk (beta) to show how the market must price individual securities in relation to their security risk class. The SML enables us to calculate the reward-to-risk ratio for any security in relation to that of the overall market. Therefore, when the expected rate of return for any security is deflated by its beta coefficient, the reward-to-risk ratio for any individual security in the market is equal to the market reward-to-risk ratio, thus:

The market reward-to-risk ratio is effectively the market risk premium and by rearranging the above equation and solving for , we obtain the capital asset pricing model (CAPM).

where:

  • is the expected return on the capital asset
  • is the risk-free rate of interest such as interest arising from government bonds
  • (the beta) is the sensitivity of the expected excess asset returns to the expected excess market returns, or also
  • is the expected return of the market
  • is sometimes known as the market premium
  • is also known as the individual risk premium
  • denotes the correlation coefficient between the investment and the market
  • is the standard deviation for the investment
  • is the standard deviation for the market .

Restated, in terms of risk premium, we find that:

which states that the individual risk premium equals the market premium times β.

Note 1: the expected market rate of return is usually estimated by measuring the arithmetic average of the historical returns on a market portfolio (e.g. S&P 500).

Note 2: the risk free rate of return used for determining the risk premium is usually the arithmetic average of historical risk free rates of return and not the current risk free rate of return.

For the full derivation see Modern portfolio theory.

Modified betas

[edit]

There has also been research into a mean-reverting beta often referred to as the adjusted beta, as well as the consumption beta. However, in empirical tests the traditional CAPM has been found to do as well as or outperform the modified beta models. [citation needed]

Security market line

[edit]

The SML graphs the results from the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) formula. The x-axis represents the risk (beta), and the y-axis represents the expected return. The market risk premium is determined from the slope of the SML.

The relationship between β and required return is plotted on the security market line (SML), which shows expected return as a function of β. The intercept is the nominal risk-free rate available for the market, while the slope is the market premium, E(Rm)? Rf. The security market line can be regarded as representing a single-factor model of the asset price, where β is the exposure to changes in the value of the Market. The equation of the SML is thus:

It is a useful tool for determining if an asset being considered for a portfolio offers a reasonable expected return for its risk. Individual securities are plotted on the SML graph. If the security's expected return versus risk is plotted above the SML, it is undervalued since the investor can expect a greater return for the inherent risk. And a security plotted below the SML is overvalued since the investor would be accepting less return for the amount of risk assumed.

Asset pricing

[edit]

Once the expected/required rate of return is calculated using CAPM, we can compare this required rate of return to the asset's estimated rate of return over a specific investment horizon to determine whether it would be an appropriate investment. To make this comparison, you need an independent estimate of the return outlook for the security based on either fundamental or technical analysis techniques, including P/E, M/B etc.

Assuming that the CAPM is correct, an asset is correctly priced when its estimated price is the same as the present value of future cash flows of the asset, discounted at the rate suggested by CAPM. If the estimated price is higher than the CAPM valuation, then the asset is overvalued (and undervalued when the estimated price is below the CAPM valuation).[5] When the asset does not lie on the SML, this could also suggest mis-pricing. Since the expected return of the asset at time is , a higher expected return than what CAPM suggests indicates that is too low (the asset is currently undervalued), assuming that at time the asset returns to the CAPM suggested price.[6]

The asset price using CAPM, sometimes called the certainty equivalent pricing formula, is a linear relationship given by

where is the future price of the asset or portfolio.[5]

Asset-specific required return

[edit]

The CAPM returns the asset-appropriate required return or discount rate—i.e. the rate at which future cash flows produced by the asset should be discounted given that asset's relative riskiness.

Betas exceeding one signify more than average "riskiness"; betas below one indicate lower than average. Thus, a more risky stock will have a higher beta and will be discounted at a higher rate; less sensitive stocks will have lower betas and be discounted at a lower rate. Given the accepted concave utility function, the CAPM is consistent with intuition—investors (should) require a higher return for holding a more risky asset.

Since beta reflects asset-specific sensitivity to non-diversifiable, i.e. market risk, the market as a whole, by definition, has a beta of one. Stock market indices are frequently used as local proxies for the market—and in that case (by definition) have a beta of one. An investor in a large, diversified portfolio (such as a mutual fund designed to track the total market), therefore, expects performance in line with the market.

Risk and diversification

[edit]

The risk of a portfolio comprises systematic risk, also known as undiversifiable risk, and unsystematic risk which is also known as idiosyncratic risk or diversifiable risk. Systematic risk refers to the risk common to all securities—i.e. market risk. Unsystematic risk is the risk associated with individual assets. Unsystematic risk can be diversified away to smaller levels by including a greater number of assets in the portfolio (specific risks "average out"). The same is not possible for systematic risk within one market. Depending on the market, a portfolio of approximately 30–40 securities in developed markets such as the UK or US will render the portfolio sufficiently diversified such that risk exposure is limited to systematic risk only. This number may vary depending on the way securities are weighted in a portfolio which alters the overall risk contribution of each security. For example, market cap weighting means that securities of companies with larger market capitalization will take up a larger portion of the portfolio, making it effectively less diversified. In developing markets a larger number of securities is required for diversification, due to the higher asset volatilities.

A rational investor should not take on any diversifiable risk, as only non-diversifiable risks are rewarded within the scope of this model. Therefore, the required return on an asset, that is, the return that compensates for risk taken, must be linked to its riskiness in a portfolio context—i.e. its contribution to overall portfolio riskiness—as opposed to its "stand alone risk". In the CAPM context, portfolio risk is represented by higher variance i.e. less predictability. In other words, the beta of the portfolio is the defining factor in rewarding the systematic exposure taken by an investor.

Efficient frontier

[edit]
The (Markowitz) efficient frontier. CAL stands for the capital allocation line.

The CAPM assumes that the risk-return profile of a portfolio can be optimized—an optimal portfolio displays the lowest possible level of risk for its level of return. Additionally, since each additional asset introduced into a portfolio further diversifies the portfolio, the optimal portfolio must comprise every asset, (assuming no trading costs) with each asset value-weighted to achieve the above (assuming that any asset is infinitely divisible). All such optimal portfolios, i.e., one for each level of return, comprise the efficient frontier.

Because the unsystematic risk is diversifiable, the total risk of a portfolio can be viewed as beta.

Assumptions

[edit]

All investors:[7]

  1. Aim to maximize economic utilities (Asset quantities are given and fixed).
  2. Are rational and risk-averse.
  3. Are broadly diversified across a range of investments.
  4. Are price takers, i.e., they cannot influence prices.
  5. Can lend and borrow unlimited amounts under the risk free rate of interest.
  6. Trade without transaction or taxation costs.
  7. Deal with securities that are all highly divisible into small parcels (All assets are perfectly divisible and liquid).
  8. Have homogeneous expectations.
  9. Have all information available all at the same time.

Problems

[edit]

In their 2004 review, economists Eugene Fama and Kenneth French argue that "the failure of the CAPM in empirical tests implies that most applications of the model are invalid".[3]

  • The traditional CAPM using historical data as the inputs to solve for a future return of asset i. However, the history may not be sufficient to use for predicting the future and modern CAPM approaches have used betas that rely on future risk estimates.[8]
  • Most practitioners and academics agree that risk is of a varying nature (non-constant). A critique of the traditional CAPM is that the risk measure used remains constant (non-varying beta). Recent research has empirically tested time-varying betas to improve the forecast accuracy of the CAPM.[9]
  • The model assumes that the variance of returns is an adequate measurement of risk. This would be implied by the assumption that returns are normally distributed, or indeed are distributed in any two-parameter way, but for general return distributions other risk measures (like coherent risk measures) will reflect the active and potential shareholders' preferences more adequately. Indeed, risk in financial investments is not variance in itself, rather it is the probability of losing: it is asymmetric in nature as in the alternative safety-first asset pricing model.[10][11] Barclays Wealth have published some research on asset allocation with non-normal returns which shows that investors with very low risk tolerances should hold more cash than CAPM suggests.[12]
  • Some investors prefer positive skewness, all things equal, which means that these investors accept lower returns when returns are positively skewed. For example, Casino gamblers pay to take on more risk. The CAPM can be extended to include co-skewness as a priced factor, besides beta.[13][14]
  • The model assumes that all active and potential shareholders have access to the same information and agree about the risk and expected return of all assets (homogeneous expectations assumption).[citation needed]
  • The model assumes that the probability beliefs of active and potential shareholders match the true distribution of returns. A different possibility is that active and potential shareholders' expectations are biased, causing market prices to be informationally inefficient. This possibility is studied in the field of behavioral finance, which uses psychological assumptions to provide alternatives to the CAPM such as the overconfidence-based asset pricing model of Kent Daniel, David Hirshleifer, and Avanidhar Subrahmanyam (2001).[15]
  • The model does not appear to adequately explain the variation in stock returns. Empirical studies show that low beta stocks offer higher returns than the model would predict.[16][17]
  • Some data to this effect was presented as early as a 1969 conference in Buffalo, New York in a paper by Fischer Black, Michael Jensen, and Myron Scholes. Either that fact is itself rational (which saves the efficient-market hypothesis but makes CAPM wrong), or it is irrational (which saves CAPM, but makes the EMH wrong – indeed, this possibility makes volatility arbitrage a strategy for reliably beating the market).[18][19][20] The puzzling empirical relationship between risk and return is also referred to as the low-volatility anomaly.
  • The model assumes that there are no taxes or transaction costs, although this assumption may be relaxed with more complicated versions of the model.[21]
  • The market portfolio consists of all assets in all markets, where each asset is weighted by its market capitalization. This assumes no preference between markets and assets for individual active and potential shareholders, and that active and potential shareholders choose assets solely as a function of their risk-return profile. It also assumes that all assets are infinitely divisible as to the amount which may be held or transacted.[citation needed]
  • The market portfolio should in theory include all types of assets that are held by anyone as an investment (including works of art, real estate, human capital...) In practice, such a market portfolio is unobservable and people usually substitute a stock index as a proxy for the true market portfolio. Unfortunately, it has been shown that this substitution is not innocuous and can lead to false inferences as to the validity of the CAPM, and it has been said that, due to the impossibility of observing the true market portfolio, the CAPM might not be empirically testable. This was presented in greater depth in a paper by Richard Roll in 1977, and is generally referred to as Roll's critique.[22] However, others find that the choice of market portfolio may not be that important for empirical tests.[23] Other authors have attempted to document what the world wealth or world market portfolio consists of and what its returns have been.[24][25][26]
  • The model assumes economic agents optimize over a short-term horizon, and in fact investors with longer-term outlooks would optimally choose long-term inflation-linked bonds instead of short-term rates as this would be a more risk-free asset to such an agent.[27][28]
  • The model assumes just two dates, so that there is no opportunity to consume and rebalance portfolios repeatedly over time. The basic insights of the model are extended and generalized in the intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM) of Robert Merton,[29] and the consumption CAPM (CCAPM) of Douglas Breeden and Mark Rubinstein.[30]
  • CAPM assumes that all active and potential shareholders will consider all of their assets and optimize one portfolio. This is in sharp contradiction with portfolios that are held by individual shareholders: humans tend to have fragmented portfolios or, rather, multiple portfolios: for each goal one portfolio — see behavioral portfolio theory[31] and Maslowian portfolio theory.[32]
  • Empirical tests show market anomalies like the size and value effect that cannot be explained by the CAPM.[33] For details see the Fama–French three-factor model.[34]

Roger Dayala[35] goes a step further and claims the CAPM is fundamentally flawed even within its own narrow assumption set, illustrating the CAPM is either circular or irrational. The circularity refers to the price of total risk being a function of the price of covariance risk only (and vice versa). The irrationality refers to the CAPM proclaimed ‘revision of prices’ resulting in identical discount rates for the (lower) amount of covariance risk only as for the (higher) amount of Total risk (i.e. identical discount rates for different amounts of risk. Roger’s findings have later been supported by Lai & Stohs.[36]

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ Sharpe, William F. (1991). "Capital Asset Prices with and without Negative Holdings". The Journal of Finance. 46 (2). [American Finance Association, Wiley]: 489–509. doi:10.2307/2328833. ISSN 0022-1082. JSTOR 2328833.
  2. ^ Chong, James; Jin, Yanbo; Phillips, Michael (April 29, 2013). "The Entrepreneur's Cost of Capital: Incorporating Downside Risk in the Buildup Method" (PDF). Retrieved 25 June 2013.
  3. ^ a b Fama, Eugene F; French, Kenneth R (Summer 2004). "The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Theory and Evidence". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 18 (3): 25–46. doi:10.1257/0895330042162430.
  4. ^ French, Craig W. (2003). "The Treynor Capital Asset Pricing Model". Journal of Investment Management. 1 (2): 60–72. SSRN 447580.
  5. ^ a b Luenberger, David (1997). Investment Science. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-510809-5.
  6. ^ Bodie, Z.; Kane, A.; Marcus, A. J. (2008). Investments (7th International ed.). Boston: McGraw-Hill. p. 303. ISBN 978-0-07-125916-3.
  7. ^ Arnold, Glen (2005). Corporate financial management (3. ed.). Harlow [u.a.]: Financial Times/Prentice Hall. p. 354.
  8. ^ French, Jordan (2016). "Back to the Future Betas: Empirical Asset Pricing of US and Southeast Asian Markets". International Journal of Financial Studies. 4 (3): 15. doi:10.3390/ijfs4030015. hdl:10419/167811.
  9. ^ French, Jordan (2016). Estimating Time-Varying Beta Coefficients: An Empirical Study of US & ASEAN Portfolios. Research in Finance. Vol. 32. pp. 19–34. doi:10.1108/S0196-382120160000032002. ISBN 978-1-78635-156-2.
  10. ^ A. D. Roy(1952), "Safety-first and the holding of assets," Econometrica, 20, No. 3, 425-442. [1]. Retrieved June 20, 2021.
  11. ^ Jansen, D. W., K.G. Koedijk and C. G. de Vries (2000), "Portfolio selection with limited downside risk," Journal of Empirical Finance, 7, 247-269.[2]. Retrieved June 20, 2021.
  12. ^ "News and insight | Wealth Management | Barclays" (PDF).
  13. ^ Kraus, Alan; Litzenberger, Robert H. (1976). "Skewness Preference and the Valuation of Risk Assets". The Journal of Finance. 31 (4): 1085–1100. doi:10.2307/2326275. ISSN 0022-1082. JSTOR 2326275.
  14. ^ Post, Thierry; van Vliet, Pim; Levy, Haim (2025-08-14). "Risk aversion and skewness preference". Journal of Banking & Finance. 32 (7): 1178–1187. doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2006.02.008. ISSN 0378-4266.
  15. ^ Daniel, Kent D.; Hirshleifer, David; Subrahmanyam, Avanidhar (2001). "Overconfidence, Arbitrage, and Equilibrium Asset Pricing". Journal of Finance. 56 (3): 921–965. doi:10.1111/0022-1082.00350.
  16. ^ Fama, Eugene F.; French, Kenneth R. (1992). "The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns". The Journal of Finance. 47 (2): 427–465. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1992.tb04398.x. ISSN 1540-6261.
  17. ^ Baltussen, Guido; van Vliet, Bart; van Vliet, Pim (2025-08-14). "The Cross-Section of Stock Returns before CRSP". SSRN Working Paper. SSRN 3969743.
  18. ^ de Silva, Harindra (2025-08-14). "Exploiting the Volatility Anomaly in Financial Markets". CFA Institute Conference Proceedings Quarterly. 29 (1): 47–56. doi:10.2469/cp.v29.n1.2. ISSN 1930-2703.
  19. ^ Baker, Malcolm; Bradley, Brendan; Wurgler, Jeffrey (2025-08-14). "Benchmarks as Limits to Arbitrage: Understanding the Low-Volatility Anomaly". Financial Analysts Journal. 67 (1): 40–54. doi:10.2469/faj.v67.n1.4. ISSN 0015-198X. S2CID 12706642.
  20. ^ Blitz, David; Van Vliet, Pim; Baltussen, Guido (2019). "The volatility effect revisited". Journal of Portfolio Management. 46 (1): jpm.2019.1.114. doi:10.3905/jpm.2019.1.114. S2CID 212976159.
  21. ^ Elton, E. J.; Gruber, M. J.; Brown, S. J.; Goetzmann, W. N. (2009). Modern portfolio theory and investment analysis. John Wiley & Sons. p. 347.
  22. ^ Roll, R. (1977). "A Critique of the Asset Pricing Theory's Tests". Journal of Financial Economics. 4 (2): 129–176. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(77)90009-5.
  23. ^ Stambaugh, Robert (1982). "On the exclusion of assets from tests of the two-parameter model: A sensitivity analysis". Journal of Financial Economics. 10 (3): 237–268. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(82)90002-2.
  24. ^ Ibbotson, Roger; Siegel, Lawrence; Love, Kathryn (1985). "World wealth: Market values and returns". Journal of Portfolio Management. 12 (1): 4–23. doi:10.3905/jpm.1985.409036. S2CID 154485834.
  25. ^ Doeswijk, Ronald; Lam, Trevin; Swinkels, Laurens (2014). "The global multi-asset market portfolio, 1960-2012". Financial Analysts Journal. 70 (2): 26–41. doi:10.2469/faj.v70.n2.1. S2CID 704936.
  26. ^ Doeswijk, Ronald; Lam, Trevin; Swinkels, Laurens (2019). "Historical returns of the market portfolio". Review of Asset Pricing Studies. X (X): XX.
  27. ^ "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2025-08-14. Retrieved 2025-08-14.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link)
  28. ^ Campbell, John Y.; Viceira, Luis M. (2002). Strategic Asset Allocation: Portfolio Choice for Long Term Investors. Clarendon Lectures in Economics. ISBN 978-0-19-829694-2.
  29. ^ Merton, R.C. (1973). "An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model". Econometrica. 41 (5): 867–887. doi:10.2307/1913811. JSTOR 1913811.
  30. ^ Breeden, Douglas (September 1979). "An intertemporal asset pricing model with stochastic consumption and investment opportunities". Journal of Financial Economics. 7 (3): 265–296. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(79)90016-3. S2CID 154918812.
  31. ^ Shefrin, H.; Statman, M. (2000). "Behavioral Portfolio Theory". Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis. 35 (2): 127–151. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.143.8443. doi:10.2307/2676187. JSTOR 2676187. S2CID 51947571.
  32. ^ De Brouwer, Ph. (2009). "Maslowian Portfolio Theory: An alternative formulation of the Behavioural Portfolio Theory". Journal of Asset Management. 9 (6): 359–365. doi:10.1057/jam.2008.35.
  33. ^ Fama, Eugene F.; French, Kenneth R. (1993). "Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds". Journal of Financial Economics. 33 (1): 3–56. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.139.5892. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(93)90023-5.
  34. ^ Fama, Eugene F.; French, Kenneth R. (1992). "The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns". Journal of Finance. 47 (2): 427–465. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.556.954. doi:10.2307/2329112. JSTOR 2329112.
  35. ^ Dayala, Roger R.S. (2012). "The Capital Asset Pricing Model: A Fundamental Critique". Business Valuation Review. 31 (1): 23–34. doi:10.5791/BVR-D-12-00001.1.
  36. ^ Lai, Tsong-Yue; Stohs, Mark H. (2015). "Yes, CAPM is dead". International Journal of Business. 20 (2): 144–158.

Bibliography

[edit]
什么盛开 阳痿吃什么中成药 手臂发麻是什么原因引起的 脾是起什么作用的 艾灸灸出水泡是什么情况
蜜蜡什么样的成色最好 馄饨皮可以做什么美食 高就什么意思 胡萝卜什么时候种植 为什么一直睡不着
拉屎肛门疼是什么原因 什么暗什么明 水光针是什么 哥哥的哥哥叫什么 坐班什么意思
劫是什么意思 tba是什么意思 东南方向是什么位置 挛缩是什么意思 什么是豆制品
拔罐是什么原理hcv9jop6ns3r.cn 两小儿辩日告诉我们什么道理zhongyiyatai.com 孕妇缺铁吃什么食物好hcv9jop7ns1r.cn 过刚易折什么意思hcv9jop6ns5r.cn jeans是什么意思hcv9jop0ns2r.cn
梦到活人死了是什么预兆xjhesheng.com 为什么不建议做肠镜cj623037.com 脑梗挂号挂什么科室gangsutong.com 什么时候拔牙最好zhongyiyatai.com 什么是寻麻疹hcv8jop9ns3r.cn
兴风作浪什么意思wzqsfys.com 赵本山什么时候去世的hcv7jop9ns7r.cn 风麻疹是什么引起的hcv9jop2ns0r.cn 屁股又叫什么bjcbxg.com 果子狸携带什么病毒fenrenren.com
频发房性早搏是什么意思hcv7jop6ns5r.cn gy是什么意思hcv8jop9ns8r.cn 肾的主要功能是什么hcv7jop6ns7r.cn 形婚是什么hcv8jop0ns0r.cn 经常吐口水是什么原因hcv9jop0ns8r.cn
百度