维多利亚是什么意思| 世界上最大的海是什么海| 礼仪是什么意思| 农历六月初六是什么星座| 川军为什么那么出名| 举人相当于什么官| 深呼吸有什么好处| lv中文名叫什么| 潮吹是什么意思| 眩晕吃什么药| 喝水牙疼是什么原因| 澳大利亚有什么特产| 择日不如撞日什么意思| 什么叫基因突变| 兔配什么生肖最好| 为什么干红那么难喝| rpa是什么| 摸头杀是什么意思| 29周岁属什么生肖| 2006年属什么生肖| 六月份是什么季节| 基础代谢是什么| 肚子硬是什么原因| 空腹胰岛素低说明什么| 脊柱侧弯有什么危害| 脑梗输液用什么药| 79年属什么生肖| 985代表什么意思| 红霉素软膏治什么病| 阴囊潮湿用什么药| 骷髅头是什么牌子| 羊肉不能和什么水果一起吃| 吃杨梅有什么好处| 海虫草是什么| 旺盛是什么意思| 什么是抗生素| 什么止痛药效果最好| 阴虚吃什么好| 下巴的痣代表什么| 梦想成真是什么意思| 脖子上长个包挂什么科| 容易紧张是什么原因| 9月10日是什么日子| 巴子是什么意思| 十五岁是什么年华| 九月七日是什么星座| 皮肤过敏吃什么药好| 照影是什么意思| 桑葚有什么作用| 痔疮不治会有什么危害| 吃什么食物补脾虚| 蚂蚁代表什么风水| 小孩缺锌有什么症状| 肠镜什么情况下取活检| 二郎神是什么生肖| 息肉样病变是什么意思| 什么是体位性低血压| 为什么游戏| 雪纳瑞什么颜色最贵| 荨麻疹是什么样的| 血症是什么病| 离岸人民币是什么意思| 小孩老是肚子疼是什么原因| 为什么正骨后几天越来越疼| 女人眼角有痣代表什么| 备孕不能吃什么| 手术后吃什么营养品好| 人中跳动是什么原因| 怀孕血糖高有什么症状| 行房时硬度不够是什么原因| 44什么意思| 癸酉五行属什么| 阴差阳错代表什么生肖| 浪琴手表属于什么档次| 心得安又叫什么名| 嘴唇干裂是什么原因引起的| 石女是什么意思| 女人戴什么招财又旺夫| 办健康证要带什么证件| 肌酐高吃什么药好| 不二法门是什么意思| 成人改名字需要什么手续| 什么食物不能一起吃| 什么叫钝痛| 地动山摇是什么生肖| 倾倒是什么意思| 敛财是什么意思| 那好吧是什么意思| 什么的春寒| 眼睛模糊用什么眼药水| 局灶癌变是什么意思| 农历十二月是什么月| 走花路是什么意思| 画什么点睛| 思钱想厚什么意思| 痔疮是什么科室看的| 什么是低聚果糖| 双鱼座的幸运色是什么颜色| 牛蛙和青蛙有什么区别| 淋巴细胞数高说明什么| 吃枸杞有什么功效| 白羊座跟什么星座最配| 娘家人是什么意思| 孕妇吃红枣对胎儿有什么好处| tommyhilfiger什么牌子| 户口本丢了有什么危害| 女性大腿酸痛什么原因| 植物是什么| 每天都做梦是什么原因| 大白片是什么药| 公主和郡主有什么区别| 什么蛇最厉害| 铁观音是属于什么茶| 推举是什么意思| 甜杆和甘蔗有什么区别| 外出是什么意思| 乳糖不耐受是什么症状| af什么意思| 淋巴细胞减少说明什么| 开什么店好| 查尿酸挂什么科| 心影饱满是什么意思| 狗狗湿疹用什么药膏最有效| 核桃补什么| 奥美拉唑和雷贝拉唑有什么区别| 尿毒症是什么病| 生肖鼠和什么生肖相冲| 压马路什么意思| 见地是什么意思| 三月阳春好风光是什么生肖| 旺是什么意思| 甲钴胺片主要治什么病| 头皮发红是什么原因| 吃什么补阳气| ha什么意思| 红细胞压积偏低是什么意思| 涎是什么意思| 赤是什么意思| 爱而不得是什么感觉| 补气补血吃什么好| 镜片什么材质好| 苦肠是什么部位| 月经前腰疼是什么原因| 卡号是什么| 空泡蝶鞍是什么病| 尿酸高有什么反应| 樱菜是什么菜| 来大姨妈为什么会拉肚子| 内分泌紊乱有什么症状表现| 粉底液是干什么用的| 抗生素药对人体有什么危害| 男生眉毛浓黑代表什么| 教师节送什么礼品| 美国为什么不禁枪| 境字五行属什么| 标新立异是什么意思| 钛合金是什么材料| 梦见吃李子是什么意思| 新生儿血糖低是什么原因| 痔疮瘙痒用什么药| 晚饭吃什么好| 什么时候开始数伏| 润六月是什么意思| 真菌性外耳道炎用什么药| 太是什么意思| 万力什么字| 罗嘉良为什么娶苏岩| 小肚子疼是什么情况| 脾胃科主要看什么| 亲子鉴定需要什么材料| 维生素b有什么作用| 萘是什么| 牛尾炖什么最好| 双顶径是指什么| 热量是什么意思| 白细胞低说明什么| 精神紊乱吃什么药| 农历5月17日是什么星座| 吃苹果有什么好处和功效| 呕吐发烧是什么原因| 中国第五大发明是什么| 七月十八是什么日子| 什么是pc| 女性尿路感染有什么症状| 口蘑不能和什么一起吃| 肌肉疼痛吃什么药| 恕是什么意思| 第一次什么感觉| 国外微信叫什么| 脚发麻是什么原因| 胎儿右肾盂分离是什么意思| 农历五月初五是什么节日| 金字旁加全字念什么| 肌酐低是什么意思啊| 鳗鱼吃什么食物| 廿是什么意思| 1963年属兔的是什么命| 什么分明| 腊梅什么时候开花| 吃什么都咸是什么原因| agoni什么意思| 中医调理身体挂什么科| 张艺谋为什么不娶巩俐| 吃什么有助于消化| 蹉跎是什么意思| 喝葡萄糖有什么功效与作用| 李时珍的皮是什么意思| 什么运动可以瘦脸| 明天我要离开是什么歌| 胆囊息肉是什么原因造成的| 空调除湿和制冷有什么区别| 鸽子和什么炖气血双补| 肛门下坠吃什么药| 腺肌症是什么病| 红颜知己是什么关系| 三点是什么时辰| 叛变是什么意思| 用进废退什么意思| 什么是拘役| 年少轻狂是什么意思| 脑梗原因是什么引起的| 自带bgm是什么意思| 小孩子坐飞机需要什么证件| 被蜱虫咬了有什么症状| 榴莲不可以和什么食物一起吃| 小黄人是什么意思| 3月2日什么星座| 噗噗噗是什么意思| 卡点是什么意思| 梦见出国了是什么意思| 闺六月是什么意思| 砂舞是什么意思| 喉咙疼吃什么药| 肺结核挂什么科| dtc是什么意思| 三什么九什么成语| 肝虚火旺吃什么中成药| 什么是打飞机| 脑供血不足用什么药| 浩瀚是什么意思| 脚气泡脚用什么泡最好| 齐多夫定片是治什么病的| 梦见捡鸡蛋是什么意思| 舅舅的老婆叫什么| 空调外机风扇不转是什么原因| 茵陈是什么| 咳嗽用什么药| 搬家有什么讲究和忌讳| 前额白发是什么原因| 现在最火的歌是什么| o型血生的孩子是什么血型| 弥陀是什么意思| 感悟是什么意思| 大片是什么意思| 终年是什么意思| 一黑一白是什么蛇| 牙垢是什么| 姝字五行属什么的| 常喝三七粉有什么好处| 加盟店是什么意思| 南瓜可以做什么美食| 为什么会堵奶| 完全性右束支传导阻滞是什么意思| 厨娘是什么意思| 百度Jump to content

楊潔篪氏、南アフリカを正式訪問

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
百度   情况紧急,豆豆先被送到当地医院进行抢救,3月18日晚10:10被转往河南省儿童医院PICU进行救治。

In microeconomics, the Bertrand–Edgeworth model of price-setting oligopoly explores what happens when firms compete to sell a homogeneous product (a good for which consumers buy only from the cheapest available seller) but face limits on how much they can supply. Unlike in the standard Bertrand competition model, where firms are assumed to meet all demand at their chosen price, the Bertrand–Edgeworth model assumes each firm has a capacity constraint: a fixed maximum output it can sell, regardless of price. This constraint may be physical (as in Edgeworth’s formulation) or may depend on price or other conditions.

A key result of the model is that pure-strategy price equilibria may fail to exist, even with just two firms, because firms have an incentive to undercut competitors' prices until they hit their capacity constraints. As a result, the model can lead to price cycles or the emergence of mixed-strategy equilibria, where firms randomize over prices.

History

[edit]

Joseph Louis Fran?ois Bertrand (1822–1900) developed the model of Bertrand competition in oligopoly. This approach was based on the assumption that there are at least two firms producing a homogenous product with constant marginal cost (this could be constant at some positive value, or with zero marginal cost as in Cournot). Consumers buy from the cheapest seller. The Bertrand–Nash equilibrium of this model is to have all (or at least two) firms setting the price equal to marginal cost. The argument is simple: if one firm sets a price above marginal cost then another firm can undercut it by a small amount (often called epsilon undercutting, where epsilon represents an arbitrarily small amount) thus the equilibrium is zero (this is sometimes called the Bertrand paradox).

The Bertrand approach assumes that firms are willing and able to supply all demand: there is no limit to the amount that they can produce or sell. Francis Ysidro Edgeworth considered the case where there is a limit to what firms can sell (a capacity constraint): he showed that if there is a fixed limit to what firms can sell, then there may exist no pure-strategy Nash equilibrium (this is sometimes called the Edgeworth paradox).[1]

Martin Shubik developed the Bertrand–Edgeworth model to allow for the firm to be willing to supply only up to its profit maximizing output at the price which it set (under profit maximization this occurs when marginal cost equals price).[2] He considered the case of strictly convex costs, where marginal cost is increasing in output. Shubik showed that if a Nash equilibrium exists, it must be the perfectly competitive price (where demand equals supply, and all firms set price equal to marginal cost). However, this can only happen if market demand is infinitely elastic (horizontal) at the competitive price. In general, as in the Edgeworth paradox, no pure-strategy Nash equilibrium will exist. Huw Dixon showed that in general a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium will exist when there are convex costs.[3] Dixon’s proof used the Existence Theorem of Partha Dasgupta and Eric Maskin.[4] Under Dixon's assumption of (weakly) convex costs, marginal cost will be non-decreasing. This is consistent with a cost function where marginal cost is flat for a range of outputs, marginal cost is smoothly increasing, or indeed where there is a kink in total cost so that marginal cost makes a discontinuous jump upwards.

[edit]

There have been several responses to the non-existence of pure-strategy equilibrium identified by Francis Ysidro Edgeworth and Martin Shubik. Whilst the existence of mixed-strategy equilibrium was demonstrated by Huw Dixon, it has not proven easy to characterize what the equilibrium actually looks like. However, Allen and Hellwig[5] were able to show that in a large market with many firms, the average price set would tend to the competitive price.

It has been argued that non-pure strategies are not plausible in the context of the Bertrand–Edgworth model. Alternative approaches have included:

  • Firms choose the quantity they are willing to sell up to at each price. This is a game in which price and quantity are chosen: as shown by Allen and Hellwig[6] and in a more general case by Huw Dixon[7] that the perfectly competitive price is the unique pure-strategy equilibrium.
  • Firms have to meet all demand at the price they set as proposed by Krishnendu Ghosh Dastidar[8] or pay some cost for turning away customers.[9] Whilst this can ensure the existence of a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium, it comes at the cost of generating multiple equilibria. However, as shown by Huw Dixon, if the cost of turning customers away is sufficiently small, then any pure-strategy equilibria that exist will be close to the competitive equilibrium.
  • Introducing product differentiation, as proposed by Jean-Pascal Benassy.[10] This is more of a synthesis of monopolistic competition with the Bertrand–Edgeworth model, but Benassy showed that if the elasticity of demand for the firms output is sufficiently high, then any pure strategy equilibrium that existed would be close to the competitive outcome.
  • "Integer pricing" as explored by Huw Dixon.[11] Rather than treat price as a continuous variable, it is treated as a discrete variable. This means that firms cannot undercut each other by an arbitrarily small amount, one of the necessary ingredients giving rise to the non-existence of a pure strategy equilibrium. This can give rise to multiple pure-strategy equilibria, some of which may be distant from the competitive equilibrium price. More recently, Prabal Roy Chowdhury[12] has combined the notion of discrete pricing with the idea that firms choose prices and the quantities they want to sell at that price as in Allen–Hellwig.
  • Epsilon equilibrium in the pure-strategy game.[13] In an epsilon equilibrium, each firm is within epsilon of its optimal price. If the epsilon is small, this might be seen as a plausible equilibrium, due perhaps to menu costs or bounded rationality. For a given , if there are enough firms, then an epsilon-equilibrium exists (this result depends on how one models the residual demand – the demand faced by higher-priced firms given the sales of the lower-priced firms).
  • Myopic Stable.[14] The Myopic Stable Set of the game offers a solution in pure strategies based on better reply dynamics. When the set of pure-strategy Nash equilibria is nonempty—such as when capacities are either sufficiently large or small—it coincides with the Myopic Stable Set. For intermediate capacity levels, the Nash equilibrium involves mixed strategies. In these cases, all prices within the support of the mixed-strategy equilibrium are included in the Myopic Stable Set. Thus, the Myopic Stable Set provides an alternative and unified foundation for understanding pricing in oligopolistic markets.

References

[edit]
  1. ^ Edgeworth, Francis (1889). "The pure theory of monopoly"., reprinted in Collected Papers relating to Political Economy. Vol. 1. Macmillan. 1925.
  2. ^ Shubik, M. (1959). Strategy and Market Structure: Competition, Oligopoly, and the Theory of Games. New York: John Wiley and Sons. ISBN 9780598679451. {{cite book}}: ISBN / Date incompatibility (help)
  3. ^ Dixon, H. D. (1984). "The existence of mixed-strategy equilibria in a price-setting oligopoly with convex costs". Economics Letters. 16 (3–4): 205–12. doi:10.1016/0165-1765(84)90164-2. hdl:10068/527249.
  4. ^ Dasgupta, P.; Maskin, E. (1986). "The Existence of Equilibrium in Discontinuous Economic Games, I: Theory". Review of Economic Studies. 53 (1): 1–26. doi:10.2307/2297588. JSTOR 2297588.
  5. ^ Allen, B.; Hellwig, M. (1986). "Bertrand–Edgeworth oligopoly in large markets". Review of Economic Studies. 53 (2): 175–204. doi:10.2307/2297646. hdl:10068/139451. JSTOR 2297646.
  6. ^ Allen, Beth; Hellwig, Martin (May 1986). "Price-Setting Firms and the Oligopolistic Foundations of Perfect Competition". Papers and Proceedings of the Ninety-Eighth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. 76 (2). American Economic Review: 387–392. JSTOR 1818802.(subscription may be required or content may be available in libraries)
  7. ^ Dixon, Huw (1992). "The Perfectly competitive outcome as the equilibrium in an Edgeworthian price–quantity game" (PDF). Economic Journal. 102 (411): 301–309. doi:10.2307/2234515. JSTOR 2234515.(subscription may be required or content may be available in libraries)
  8. ^ Dastidar, Krishnendu Ghosh (January 1995). "On the Existence of Pure Strategy Bertrand Equilibrium". Journal of Economic Theory. 5 (1). Springer: 19–32. doi:10.1007/bf01213642. S2CID 153890403.
  9. ^ Dixon, Huw (December 1990). "Bertrand–Edgeworth Equilibria when Firms Avoid Turning Customers Away". Journal of Industrial Economics. 39 (2). Wiley-Blackwell: 131–46. doi:10.2307/2098489. JSTOR 2098489.(subscription may be required or content may be available in libraries)
  10. ^ Benassy, Jean-Pascal (April 1989). "Market Size and Substitutability in Imperfect Competition: A Bertrand–Edgeworth–Chamberlin Model". Review of Economic Studies. 56 (2). Wiley–Blackwell: 217–34. doi:10.2307/2297458. JSTOR 2297458.(subscription may be required or content may be available in libraries)
  11. ^ Dixon, Huw David (July 1993). "Integer Pricing and Bertrand–Edgeworth Oligopoly with Strictly Convex Costs: Is It Worth More Than a Penny?". Bulletin of Economic Research. 45 (3). Wiley–Blackwell: 257–68. doi:10.1111/j.1467-8586.1993.tb00570.x.
  12. ^ Chowdhury, P. R. (May 2008). "Equilibrium with a large number of firms". International Journal of Industrial Organization. 26 (3): 746–761. doi:10.1016/j.ijindorg.2007.05.009.(subscription may be required or content may be available in libraries)
  13. ^ Dixon, H. (1987). "Approximate Bertrand Equilibria in a replicated Industry". Review of Economic Studies. 54 (1): 47–62. doi:10.2307/2297445. JSTOR 2297445.(subscription may be required or content may be available in libraries)
  14. ^ Bos, Iwan; Marini, Marco; Saulle, Riccardo D. (2024). "Myopic Oligopoly Pricing". Games and Economic Behavior: 377–412. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2024.03.014. hdl:11577/3520425. ISSN 1573-7187.(subscription may be required or content may be available in libraries)

Resources

[edit]
七夕节是什么时候 性生活频繁有什么危害 刘玄德属什么生肖 端倪是什么意思 争奇斗艳的斗是什么意思
三个金念什么 年轻人创业做什么好 训练有素是什么意思 异的偏旁是什么 口腔溃疡看什么科室
时兴是什么意思 立秋是什么时候 为什么一睡觉就做梦 血小板低吃什么食物补得快 丹毒是什么原因引起的
情志是什么意思 长脸适合什么耳环 慢性心肌炎有什么症状 宰相的宰最早指什么 急忙的反义词是什么
李维斯属于什么档次hcv8jop3ns1r.cn 早泄要吃什么药naasee.com 晨勃消失是什么原因hcv9jop3ns1r.cn 流产的血是什么颜色hcv8jop4ns2r.cn 做梦梦到掉牙齿是什么意思hcv8jop6ns5r.cn
便秘是什么症状chuanglingweilai.com 与虎谋皮是什么意思hcv8jop3ns3r.cn 什么腿hcv8jop2ns8r.cn 副研究员什么级别1949doufunao.com 小心的什么hcv9jop0ns0r.cn
栀子对妇科有什么功效hcv7jop9ns1r.cn 为什么要做羊水穿刺检查hcv7jop6ns2r.cn fml什么意思chuanglingweilai.com 龙脉是什么意思hcv7jop6ns5r.cn 电镀是做什么的hcv9jop3ns6r.cn
长期手淫会有什么危害hcv9jop7ns1r.cn 百废待兴是什么意思0735v.com 嘴巴长疱疹是什么原因hcv8jop9ns2r.cn 黄瓜籽粉有什么作用hcv7jop6ns8r.cn 男人秒射是什么原因hcv9jop1ns8r.cn
百度